Is a Reduction in Rates of
Taxation Likely to Lead to an Improvement in Productivity? (August 2005)
I have been
somewhat bemused over recent months by the amount of media coverage
given to the taxation policies of the major political parties, and the
way in which taxation has become a vote buyer.
The media and
politicians have overlooked two simple facts:
·
In the current
environment, reductions in rates of taxation on personal income will to
a large extent be used for the purchase of consumables and will likely
promote inflation; and
·
Reductions in the rate
of taxation on business income will not necessarily encourage
manufacturers to invest in new plant and machinery.
I will let those
more knowledgeable debate the likely impact of tax cuts on inflation and
instead concentrate on the implications of the proposed tax cuts for
manufacturers.
The media are
regularly providing us with examples of companies that cannot compete
with overseas manufacturers and are shifting production off shore,
usually to China. In many instances, they cannot compete because they
have obsolete plant and machinery while the Chinese are using the latest
technology available to them. Comparative labour rates are also a factor
in this equation, but this is not as significant as it was.
A cut in tax
rates is not going to help redress the balance. It is a given that the
higher a company’s taxable income, the greater the benefit obtained from
a reduction in the company tax rate. It is also a given that many new
ventures often do not have significant pre-tax profits. As a result they
will gain little or no financial benefit from a drop in tax rates, and
will have little extra to invest in state of the art plant and
machinery.
With many of our
major companies being owned by offshore investors, any reduction in
rates of taxation will lead to the offshore owners of many New Zealand
based companies enjoying substantial benefits. Conversely, the changes
will not provide any substantial benefit to many of the New Zealand
owned enterprises the government is exhorting to improve their
productivity.
What is required
is a revision of the whole depreciation regime to more accurately
reflect the economic life of plant and machinery. The useful economic
life of, say, a lathe fifty years ago bears no relationship to the
economic useful life of a current CNC item. Economic obsolescence is a
factor today. It was not so to the same extent fifty years ago.
If our
competitors are replacing their plant and equipment on a five-yearly
cycle, so should we if we are to become internationally competitive. Our
depreciation rates should reflect the economic, as opposed to the
physical, life of assets. Admittedly this could increase overhead
recovery rates for individual businesses, but this should be more than
offset by increased productivity.
We are constantly
informed that New Zealand companies must raise their productivity if we
are to be competitive in international markets. The current emphasis on
tax cuts will not encourage this. An intelligent approach to the
determination of depreciation rates, and policies aligned with the
economic realities of global competitiveness will. It will reward those
who invest in new plant and equipment, and assist in raising
productivity levels.
In summary:
·
Reductions in the rate
of taxation on business profits favours companies with high levels of
profits;
·
A considerable number of
New Zealand’s largest companies are overseas owned. Reductions in
taxation rates could lead to an increase in dividend flows to the
offshore owners, not to investment in new plant and machinery in New
Zealand.
·
Many of New Zealand’s
new innovative companies have low levels of profit. They will make
minimal gains from a reduction in business tax rates.
·
Reductions in business
tax rates do not in themselves lead to an increase in investment in new
capital equipment.
·
New Zealand’s
depreciation regime for tax purposes is predicated on the physical life
of assets. This takes no account of their true economic life.
·
Economic obsolescence is
a fact of life today and we should be looking at significant changes in
the depreciation rates applied for tax purposes.
·
Accelerated rates of
depreciation can be an incentive for manufacturers to maintain modern
machinery more in keeping with that used by their overseas competitors.
·
Failure to provide
incentives for manufacturers to invest in new plant and machinery will
see more companies move production offshore.
·
The shift of production
offshore has a knock-on effect as many of our remaining manufacturers
are reliant upon those companies as suppliers or customers.